Page 1 of 26
Online Appendix
A The Optimal Knowledge Stock
The firm then chooses the optimal Ki that maximizes global net profits,
i ≠ c (Ki), i.e.
max zi
Y
]
[
ÿ
n
S
U
A ›Ki
·jmn B‡≠1
Bin
T
V ≠ ÂKk
i
Z
^
\
The first order condition is
(‡ ≠ 1) K‡≠2
i
ÿ
n
S
U
A ›
·jmn B‡≠1
Bin
T
V = kÂKk≠1
i
Ki = Ÿ
Aÿ
n
· 1≠‡ jmnBinB1/[k≠(‡≠1)]
,
where Ÿ © [›‡≠1 (‡ ≠ 1) / (kÂ)]1/[k≠(‡≠1)].
The second order condition is, inserting the expression for the optimal Ki,
(‡ ≠ 1) (‡ ≠ 2) K‡≠3
i
ÿ
n
S
U
A ›
·jmn B‡≠1
Bin
T
V ≠ k (k ≠ 1) ÂKk≠2
i < 0
Ÿk≠(‡≠1) (‡ ≠ 2) K‡≠3
i
ÿ
n
Ë
· 1≠‡ jmnBinÈ
≠ (k ≠ 1) Kk≠2
i < 0
(‡ ≠ 2) K‡≠3
i Kk≠(‡≠1)
i ≠ (k ≠ 1) Kk≠2
i < 0
(‡ ≠ 1 ≠ k) Kk≠2
i < 0
which holds given that k ≠ (‡ ≠ 1) > 0.
B Fixed Exporting Costs
This section develops an extension of the benchmark model with fixed costs of exporting. In
order to serve a market, a firm i must incur a fixed cost f (n) to market n. Net profits selling
40
Page 2 of 26
to n are then fii (n)=(z/·jm (n))‡≠1 Bi (n) ≠ f (n). For analytical convenience, consider
the case with a unit continuum of countries. Without loss of generality, countries are sorted
according to their profitability, fiim (n), from high to low.
The firm faces two choices: first, how much to innovate and second, where to sell. We
start with the second problem. Because of the presence of market-specific fixed costs, firms
will only export to countries that give them positive net profits, fiim (n) > 0. Label the
destination with zero profits n ̄i, i.e. fiijm ( ̄ni)=0. Global profits are then
i =
⁄ n ̄i
0
S
U
A zi
·jm (n)
B‡≠1
Bi (n) ≠ f (n)
T
V dn.
We now turn to the problem of how much to innovate. Maximizing
i ≠c (Ki) and using
Leibniz’ integral rule yields
Ki = Ÿ
3⁄ n ̄i
0
·jm (n)
1≠‡ Bi (n) dn41/[k≠(‡≠1)]
.
In changes, we obtain
Kˆi =
C⁄ n ̄i
Õ
0
Êij (n) ˆ·jm (n)
1≠‡ Bˆi (n) dnD1/[k≠(‡≠1)]
,
where n ̄Õ is the marginal destination country in the counterfactual equilibrium and Êij (n) is
the gross profit shares in the initial equilibrium,
Êij (n) = ·jm (n)
1≠‡ Bi (n)
s n ̄
0 ·jm (o)
1≠‡ Bi (o) do.
We observe that when n ̄Õ
i = ̄ni, we get a similar expression as equation (2) in the main text.
41
Page 3 of 26
C Approximation of the Knowledge Production Function
The expression Kˆi = 1q
n ÊinBˆin·ˆ1≠‡ jmn21/[k≠(‡≠1)] can be approximated by equation (3) in
the main text,
ln Ki = — q
nœ
i Êin
Tjmn + Ái, where — © (1 ≠ ‡) / [k ≠ (‡ ≠ 1)] and
Ái © [k ≠ (‡ ≠ 1)]≠1 q
n Êin
ln Bin.
Proof. The term
ÿ
n
ÊinBˆin·ˆ1≠‡ jmn = ÿ
n
Êine(1≠‡)
ln ·jmn+
ln Bin
¥ ÿ
n
Êin (1 + (1 ≠ ‡)
ln ·jmn +
ln Bin)
= 1+ ÿ
n
Êin ((1 ≠ ‡)
ln ·jmn +
ln Bin),
where we used the fact that ln (1 + x) ¥ x ≈∆ 1 + x ¥ ex for x close to 0. Hence,
ln Ki = 1
k ≠ (‡ ≠ 1) ln C
1 + ÿ
n
Êin ((1 ≠ ‡)
ln ·jmn +
ln Bin)
D
¥
1
k ≠ (‡ ≠ 1)
ÿ
n
Êin ((1 ≠ ‡)
ln ·jmn +
ln Bin)
= 1
k ≠ (‡ ≠ 1) A
(1 ≠ ‡)
ÿ
n
Êin
Tjmn + ÿ
n
Êin
ln BinB
,
where we used
ln ·jmn =
ln (1 + Tjmn) ¥
Tjmn for Tjmn close to 0.
We evaluate the performance of the approximation using a numerical example. We
evaluate the true and approximated knowledge production functions in equations (2) and
(3) in the main text, respectively. Figure 4 shows the change in log knowledge production,
ln Ki, as a function of the tari
in the new equilibrium, T1, under the assumption that the
initial tari
is 20 percent, T0 = 0.2. Given a slope coe
cient — = ≠1, the approximation
performs well, especially for relatively small changes in tari
s. If there is more curvature,
i.e. — > ≠1 or — < ≠1, the approximation performs worse, especially for large changes in
tari
s.
42